UNITED STATES
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION
Washington, D.C. 20549
SCHEDULE 14A
(Rule 14a-101)
Proxy Statement Pursuant to Section 14(a) of the Securities
Exchange Act of 1934 (Amendment No. )
Filed by the Registrant [X]
|
Filed by a Party other than the Registrant [ ]
|
Check the appropriate box:
|
[ ] |
Preliminary Proxy Statement
|
[ ]
|
Confidential, for Use of the Commission Only (as permitted by Rule 14a-6(e)(2))
|
[ ] |
Definitive Proxy Statement
|
[X]
|
Definitive Additional Materials
|
[ ]
|
Soliciting Material Pursuant to §240.14a-12
|
Honeywell International Inc.
|
(Name of Registrant as Specified In Its Charter)
|
|
|
(Name of Person(s) Filing Proxy Statement, if other than the Registrant)
|
Payment of Filing Fee (Check the appropriate box):
[X] |
No fee required. |
|
|
[ ] |
Fee computed on
table below per Exchange Act Rules 14a-6(i)(1) and 0-11. |
|
|
|
|
1) |
Title of each class of securities to which transaction applies: |
|
|
|
|
2) |
Aggregate number of securities to which transaction applies: |
|
|
|
|
3) |
Per unit price or other underlying
value of transaction computed pursuant to Exchange Act Rule 0-11 (set forth
the amount on which the filing fee is calculated and state how it was determined): |
|
|
|
|
4) |
Proposed maximum aggregate value of transaction: |
|
|
|
|
5) |
Total fee paid: |
|
|
|
|
[ ] |
Fee previously paid with preliminary
materials. |
|
|
[ ] |
Check box if any part of the fee is
offset as provided by Exchange Act Rule 0-11(a)(2) and identify the filing
for which the offsetting fee was paid previously. Identify the previous
filing by registration statement number, or the Form or Schedule and the
date of its filing. |
|
|
|
1) |
Amount Previously Paid: |
|
|
|
|
2) |
Form, Schedule or Registration Statement No. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
3) |
Filing Party: |
|
|
|
|
4) |
Date Filed: |
|
|
Accelerated Vesting in Takeovers:
The Impact on Shareholder Wealth
Susan Elkinawy and David Offenberg*
|
|
|
|
|
|
We study the impact of accelerated vesting of equity
awards on takeovers, whereby the restricted stock and/or stock options of the
target chief executive officer (CEO) immediately vest and become unrestricted
upon the close of the acquisition. We find that takeover premiums are
significantly larger when the target CEO receives the benefit of accelerated
vesting as compared to target firms with CEOs that continue to vest in their
awards after closing the deal. Our evidence suggests that these cash
windfalls triggered by accelerated vesting are beneficial to shareholders in
completed deals. Accelerated vesting appears to be an efficient form of ex
ante managerial contracting.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
When
Caesars Entertainment was acquired by Harrahs in 2005, the chief executive
officer (CEO) of Caesars, Wallace Barr, received a payday of nearly $20
million. Mr. Barrs new-found riches were the result of the acceleration of
vesting provisions on his stock options and restricted stock. For instance,
Caesars 1998 Stock Incentive Plan, under which Mr. Barrs options were
granted, stipulated that in the event of a Change in Control, any Stock Options
and Stock Appreciation Rights outstanding as of the date such Change in Control
is determined to have occurred, and which are not then exercisable and vested,
shall become fully exercisable and vested. The New York Times described Mr.
Barr and similarly situated CEOs as becoming truly, titanically, stupefyingly
rich.1 Despite the rhetoric in the popular press about CEO
windfalls due to accelerated vesting provisions, there is no evidence to date
about whether these contractual terms hurt shareholder wealth.
We define
accelerated vesting as a change in the vesting schedule for the CEOs stock
options and restricted stock that results in such equity grants becoming vested
and unrestricted as of the close of the acquisition.2 For our
purposes, stock options include stock appreciation rights, warrants, and all
other equity-based incentives that behave like stock options for the recipient.
Likewise, restricted stock includes phantom stock and similar instruments. When
the CEO receives the benefit of accelerated vesting, they have the right to
convert certain equity grants to cash on the date that the firm is acquired.
Our goal in this
paper is to study the impact that accelerated vesting of the CEOs stock
options and restricted stock has upon the premium received by target firm
shareholders when their firm is acquired. In particular, we test two alternate
hypotheses. The first, the Incentive Alignment
|
|
The
authors thank Mehmet Akbulut, Hsin-Hui Chiu, Bill Christie (Editor), Josh
Finkenberg, Yi Jiang, Micah Officer, and two anonymous referees, as well as
seminar participants at Loyola Marymount University, the 2011 California
Corporate Finance Conference, and the 2011 Western Economics Association
conference for their helpful comments and suggestions. We also thank Katie
Belsky, Steve Snyder, and Kelsey Stricker for their research assistance.
|
*Susan Elkinawy is an
Associate Professor in the Department of Finance and CIS at Loyola Marymount
University in Los Angeles, CA. David Offenberg is an Assistant Professor in the
Department of Finance and CIS at Loyola Marymount University in Los Angeles,
CA.
1 No Wonder CEOs Love Those Mergers by
Gretchen Morgenson, July 18, 2004, p. 1.
2 Aboody (1996) and Brisley (2006) provide
more information about the vesting of equity grants.
Financial
Management xxxx 2012 pages 1 - 26
|
|
2
|
Financial
Management XXX 2012
|
|
|
|
Hypothesis,
suggests accelerated vesting induces CEOs to bargain for higher premiums as
they receive a larger payoff as their options get deeper in the money and
restricted stock converts at a higher multiple. The second, the Risk Aversion
Hypothesis, argues that CEOs are willing to trade a lower premium for
certainty in completing the deal since accelerated vesting allows the CEO to
cash out and reduce their exposure to risk. The significance of the deal to
the target CEO is the value of the takeover premium plus the value of their
private risk reduction via accelerated vesting. In other words, the CEOs
reservation value may be met by a combination of a reduced premium and risk
reduction.
|
This
study is feasible since not all CEOs receive the benefit of accelerated
vesting when their firm is acquired. Changes in the Security and Exchange
Commissions (SECs) disclosure rules for CEO compensation contracts starting
in 2004 allow us to determine whether or not the CEOs unvested equity
becomes vested at the close of the deal. We test our two competing hypotheses
on a sample of 107 takeovers from 2005 to 2009, 80 (75%) of which result in
accelerated vesting.3
|
We
find support for the Incentive Alignment Hypothesis. Using various
specifications of Schwert (1996)-inspired takeover premiums that include both
the run-up and the mark-up, we find that the premiums received by firms with
accelerated vesting are nearly double those received by firms without
accelerated vesting, 30.6% versus 15.4%. The robustness of this result is
documented in regression models that offer further evidence that accelerated
vesting increases takeover premiums. Our evidence suggests that target CEOs
who become titanically rich also make their shareholders wealthier.
|
A
study of accelerated vesting is particularly timely in light of §951 of the Dodd-Frank Financial Reform Act.
This section of the new law states that when a firm is being taken over, its
shareholders must approve any payments to named executives that are
contingent upon a change in control, such as accelerated vesting of
restricted stock and stock options. (While the verbiage of the law states
that the payments are subject to shareholder vote, it also notes that the
vote is nonbinding.) If shareholders have not already approved the
accelerated vesting provisions prior to the takeover announcement, the
shareholder vote is to be held simultaneously, but separately from the
shareholder vote to approve the change in control.4 Our evidence
suggests that shareholders should vote in favor of accelerated vesting in ex
ante contracts.
|
This
study contributes to a growing literature on the impact of target executive
compensation in acquisitions, and is also timely in light of evidence
presented in Fich, Cai, and Tran (2011) and Heitzman (2011). Hartzell, Ofek,
and Yermack (2004) describe the gains from stock and options as the largest
component of overall gains obtained by [target] CEOs. Hartzell et al. (2004)
find that premiums are lower in deals where the CEO negotiates a large, fixed
cash payment as part of the merger agreement. Fich et al. (2011) determine
that premiums are lower in deals in which the CEO is unexpectedly granted
stock options after the deal is announced, but before it closes. In other
words, their evidence collectively suggests that bribing the CEO to get the
deal done results in an economic loss to target shareholders. We find that
premiums are actually higher in deals in which the target CEO receives a
windfall. The difference in findings may be due to differences in the ex ante
efficiency of managerial compensation contracts.
|
|
|
3
If the CEO does
not receive accelerated vesting on their equity grants, then the stock
options (restricted stock) convert to stock options (restricted stock) of the
acquirer.
|
4
This provision of
the financial reform law appears to have been inserted at the urging of
labor, consumer rights, and shareholder rights groups. For instance, the
organization Americans for Financial Reform claimed that accelerated
vesting bring(s) little or no value to shareholders, impose(s) an economic
cost on the company and can reflect a Boards misplaced allegiance to the
Chief Executive rather than the shareholders. See
http://ourfinancialsecurity.org/2009/07/executive-compensation/.
|
|
|
Elkinawy & Offenberg Accelerated
Vesting in Takeovers
|
3
|
|
|
|
Executive
compensation scholars have also recently taken an interest in the process by
which equity incentives are granted and vested. Heron and Lie (2007) study
the backdating of stock options at the grant date before and after the
Sarbanes-Oxley reforms of 2002. Fu and Ligon (2010) document that CEOs are
more likely to exercise their options on the vesting date, rather than the
expiration date. Laux (2010) theoretically demonstrates that longer vesting
periods can reduce the CEOs incentive to invest in long-term projects. In
contrast, Chi and Johnson (2011) empirically find firm value and performance
are positively correlated with the length of the vesting period. Our research
complements and extends this literature as well.
|
To
the best of our knowledge, this is the first paper to explore the impact of
accelerated vesting of stock options and restricted stock on target premiums.
Past studies have looked more broadly at golden parachutes, which can include
various forms of nonequity-related cash payments and other benefits. Machlin,
Choe, and Miles (1993) find that golden parachutes increase takeover
premiums, whereas Cotter and Zenner (1994) find no such correlation.
|
Our
paper is also similar to Lefanowicz, Robinson, and Smith (2000), but with a
few key differences. Lefanowicz et al. (2000) collect data on the vesting of
all forms of deferred compensation, not just options and restricted stock.
However, they do not differentiate between accelerated vesting on equity
incentives and other forms of deferred compensation (qualified and
nonqualified deferred compensation plans, performance bonus plans, etc.).
Furthermore, they only search for accelerated vesting provisions in the
proxy, while we find such terms embedded in many other types of documents as
described in detail in Section II, so they do not have an accurate measure of
accelerated vesting. Finally, they do not measure the impact of accelerated
vesting on the acquisition premium, as we do here.
|
The
remainder of the study is organized as follows. Section I reviews the
relevant literature and hypotheses. Section II describes our methodology for
building our sample. Section III presents our empirical findings, while
Section IV discusses our findings. Section V presents our conclusions.
|
|
|
I.
|
Background
|
|
|
A.
|
Literature
Review
|
|
Research
on acquisitions has generally found that target shareholders fare well if the
takeover is successful. However, Jensen (1988) indicates that the managers of
the target firm can lose their position or otherwise suffer sizable losses in
compensation as a result of a successful tender offer. Thus, management of
the target firm will frequently try to prevent the takeover or the CEO will
bargain with the bidding firm to keep their job. These types of actions are
typically not in the best interests of the target shareholders, leading many
firms to implement compensation schemes to provide the proper managerial
incentives, one of which includes the accelerated vesting of restricted stock
and stock options.
|
Stulz
(1988) builds a model that demonstrates a positive correlation between
managerial equity ownership and takeover premiums. In his model, the equity
owned by the managers has additional value due to the attached voting rights.
However, stock options and restricted stock do not have voting rights, so
they do not behave like the equity in Stulzs (1988) model. Furthermore,
equity grants are not uniformly viewed as being an effective agency
management tool. Bettis et al. (2010) examine 983 equity-based awards and
find that performance-vesting provisions are associated with subsequently
better operating performance than firms without these provisions.5 Billett,
|
|
|
5 When equity awards are subject to
performance vesting, ownership of the equity typically transfers to the
executive if certain performance benchmarks are met.
|
|
4
|
Financial
Management XXX 2012
|
|
|
|
Mauer,
and Zhang (2010) similarly find positive stock returns around the first
equity grant to a CEO, and Zhang (2009) determines that the CEOs stock
options help mitigate agency costs. In contrast, Moeller (2005) finds no
correlation between CEO stock option holdings and takeover premiums. Brown
and Lee (2010) confirm a negative relationship between firm governance and
the value of stock options and restricted stock that they attribute to the
ability of a powerful CEO to extract higher compensation than is economically
justifiable.
|
With
regard to the threat of takeover, Stein (1989) suggests that a managers fear
of their firms acquisition can cause the manager to focus on short-term
stock prices. Chi and Johnson (2011) indicate that the risk to shareholders
is that the focus on short-term results could override the contractual
vesting period. Chi and Johnson (2011) examine the length of vesting periods
and find that longer vesting periods do result in better managerial
decision-making and higher share price reactions to acquisition
announcements, but they examine the abnormal returns to the acquirer rather
than the target. It is less clear whether the vesting structure of the target
CEOs equity compensation is associated with wealth gains for the target
shareholders. If accelerated vesting provides the proper managerial
incentives, all else being equal, we would expect a higher takeover premium
for firms implementing this type of scheme.
|
As
several authors point out, the takeover premium is also related to the
expectations of the target CEO upon completion of the merger. Lefanowicz et
al. (2000) find that target managers negotiate for higher premiums to
compensate for lost salary suggesting that managers who do not expect future
employment will actually bargain more heavily for the shareholders. However,
the takeover premium is lower with the presence of a golden parachute
implying that golden parachute payments reduce the incentive for target
managers to get the best deal for their shareholders. Hartzell et al. (2004)
confirm that target CEOs will accept a lower acquisition premium in exchange
for special treatment postmerger, including cash bonuses and a position in
the merged firm. Similarly, Wulf (2004) determines that target CEOs who share
control rights postmerger are willing to accept a lower premium. Cai and Vijh
(2007) find that liquidity concerns related to the stock and option holdings
of a target CEO can motivate that CEO to accept a lower premium in an
acquisition. These papers collectively suggest that target CEOs trade private
future benefits for a lower acquisition premium.
|
In
contrast to the previous studies suggesting opportunism by the target CEO at
the expense of the target shareholders, Bargeron et al. (2009) find that
target managers do not trade off future employment benefits in the merged
firm for a lower premium. Their results indicate that the acquisition premium
is actually higher when the target manager is retained, although this is only
true when the acquisition is initiated by a private bidder. They attribute
their findings to possible managerial synergies that override the incentives
of target managers to bribe the target shareholders. The fact that this
finding does not hold for public acquirers suggests different negotiating
tactics and/or different considerations faced by the target CEO and their
board. Overall, these studies reveal the complexity of the source of the
takeover premium. Our paper attempts to isolate the effect of one element
that is likely to influence the incentives of the target CEO in the
acquisition process.
|
|
|
B.
|
Hypotheses
|
|
|
In
this section, we develop two alternative hypotheses that describe how
accelerated vesting provisions should impact acquisition premiums. The
Incentive Alignment Hypothesis is based on the theory of agency costs
discussed in Jensen and Meckling (1976). The agency problem arises from the
divergence of interests between the manager and the shareholders as the
manager is not the owner of the firm. Therefore, the manager will maximize
their own utility through
|
|
|
Elkinawy & Offenberg Accelerated
Vesting in Takeovers
|
5
|
|
|
|
nonpecuniary
benefits because they only bear a fraction of the cost of these perquisites.
In order to offset the incentive to expropriate corporate resources, the
board can structure part of the managers pay to include stock options and/or
direct shares in the firm that convert to cash upon a change in control. This
compensation scheme better aligns the interests of the manager with that of
the outside equity holders since the wealth of the manager is tied to share
price. With regard to acquisitions, incentive alignment suggests that
accelerated vesting of equity awards will induce the target CEO to negotiate
for the highest possible premium.
|
Our
alternate hypothesis is based upon risk aversion, which suggests that target
CEOs may accept a lower premium from a bidding firm because the CEO gains
value from the deal in two ways: 1) the premium and 2) the private value of
risk reduction. In fact, there are many risk factors that the CEO can
mitigate by cashing out equity via accelerated vesting in a takeover. First,
the CEO gets the benefit of diversification. The CEO gets to choose how their
wealth is invested, rather than being forced to invest in the acquirer.
Additionally, the CEOs equity grants are no longer exposed to forfeiture.
Under a typical vesting schedule, if the employee leaves the firm before the
equity grant has vested, all unvested awards are forfeited. However, with
accelerated vesting, all awards convert to cash, so there is no longer a risk
of forfeiture. Moreover, the equity holdings of the CEO will no longer be
susceptible to public disclosure in the proxy statement. As a result, the CEO
gains privacy and the benefit of not having their trades scrutinized by
investors. Accelerated vesting also offers the benefit of an immediate cash
payment at a higher stock price. As a result, if risk aversion is the
motivating factor for target CEOs, we would expect the takeover premium to be
the same or lower for firms with accelerated vesting as for firms without it.
|
|
|
II.
|
Methodology
|
|
|
A.
|
Regulatory
Framework
|
|
This
study is now possible due to recent changes in SEC regulations that made more
executive compensation data available. Starting in late 2004, SEC Rule
33-8400 required firms to publicly disclose a description of the material
terms of any employment agreement between the company and the [chief
executive] officer. The terms of the contract were typically disclosed in
item 5.02(c) of an 8-k filing. A review of these documents on electronic
data-gathering analysis retrieval (EDGAR) suggests that most firms found it
was less costly to disclose the entire contract, rather than paying lawyers
to write a detailed summary. In almost all of the cases we reviewed, the
entire contract is posted, less personal information. Although SEC Rule
33-8765, approved in 2006, altered the filing requirements slightly,
companies continued to submit the entire compensation contract for public
viewing. There are now a wealth of historical employment contracts and change
of control agreements, available on the SECs EDGAR website. Many of these
contracts are explicitly described as confidential, some with shocking levels
of personal information.6
|
There
is no regulation that sets a time frame over which a CEO becomes vested in
his equity incentives in the normal course of business without a change in
control. Rather, ownership of the restricted stock and options transfers from
the company to the CEO according to a schedule in the appropriate agreement.
For instance, according to the terms of his employment agreement signed on
November 19, 2002, Wallace Barr of Caesars was scheduled to become vested in
his options at a rate of 25% per year. He would be fully vested after four
years. He was scheduled to vest in his restricted stock at a rate of 20%
after the first and second years, and 30% after his
|
|
|
6 The authors
found one document that contained an executives home address and passport
number.
|
|
6
|
Financial Management XXX 2012
|
|
third
and fourth years. The majority of the documents that we read had vesting
schedules in a range from three to five years. Of course, the accelerated
vesting initiated by a change of control supersedes a predetermined vesting
schedule and creates an immediate payoff.
It
is important to note that compensation received through accelerated vesting is
technically a golden parachute, as defined by the Internal Revenue Service
(IRS). However, the empirical research on golden parachutes to date, such as
Machlin et al. (1993) and Cotter and Zenner (1994), specifically studies lump
sum cash severance and bonus payments only, and ignores the equity portion of
the compensation. The key difference between accelerated vesting payments and
broader golden parachute payments is the floating versus fixed nature of the
cash flow. Most golden parachute provisions provide a fixed dollar amount upon
a change in control, whereas accelerated vesting payments are determined by the
size of the takeover premium, which, in turn, is determined by the CEOs
actions.
As
in Lefanowicz et al. (2000), we form our sample from firms that have been
delisted from Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) for reasons of an
acquisition. The sample is constructed by first identifying publicly traded,
nonregulated US firms that were delisted from CRSP in the five years from 2005
to 2009, with CRSP delisting codes in the range from 231 to 271. These
delisting codes indicate firms that were acquired. The acquired firms were then
matched to Compustat, to add in financial data, and Execucomp, to add in data
on the CEO. That matching produced a sample of 122 firms. We further eliminate
two reverse mergers. Finally, we read through the remaining 120 firms filings
on the SECs EDGAR website to determine if provisions were in place to
accelerate vesting before the deals commenced. We were able to find sufficient
documents for 107 of the 120 firms. This is our final sample. By comparison,
Wulf (2004) has a sample size of 40, and Hartzell et al. (2004) has a sample
size of 239.7 The firms in our sample are drawn from the ExecuComp
universe, so they are primarily drawn from the S&P indices. One quarter of
the firms belongs to the S&P 500, one-sixth is members of the S&P
Midcap 400, and about half are part of the S&P Smallcap 600. Arguably, this
is a diverse and representative sample of publicly traded firms.8
In
searching the EDGAR database, we consider all possible documents that may offer
the terms of accelerated vesting for the CEO. We find definitive language in a
wide variety of documents including employment contracts and change of control
agreements, as well as equity award notifications, proxy statements, equity
incentive plan documents, and annual reports. We code a firm as participating
in accelerated vesting if provisions were in place to accelerate the CEOs
vesting before the Agreement and Plan of Merger was signed. Of our 107 firms,
80 accelerate vesting (75% of our sample) and 27 do not.
The
control variables used in this study are motivated by previous research on the
source of takeover premia. The financial variables are calculated as follows.
The market-to-book ratio divides the quantity of price (Compustat variable PRCCF)
times number of shares of common stock outstanding (CSHO) by the book value of
the common stock (CEQ). This variable captures the target firms growth
opportunities. The cash to sales ratio divides cash and equivalents (CHE) by
sales (SALE). Long-term debt to assets divides long-term debt (DLTT) by the
market value of assets [(DLTT+DLC) + PRCCF*CSHO + PSTKL (TXDC +
ITCI)]. Fich et al. (2011)
7
Later, in Section III.C of this paper, we further extend our sample by
adding 91 matching unacquired firms, increasing our sample size to 198
observations.
8
While our firms are predictably larger than the 388 non-Execucomp firms
delisted in CRSP from 2005 to 2009, they do not have significantly different
leverage ratios, market-to-book ratios, or cash-to-sales ratios (unreported).
|
|
Elkinawy & Offenberg Accelerated
Vesting in Takeovers
|
7
|
|
document
a positive association between leverage and the acquisition premium. All of
these values are calculated at the end of the fiscal year immediately preceding
the takeover.
The
age of each CEO is collected from Execucomp. When those data are missing, we
search proxy statements and Lexis/Nexis for the age. We were able to find ages
for all 107 of our CEOs. Fich et al. (2011) find that acquisition premiums are
lower when a CEO is near retirement (age 62 or older). Tenure is calculated as
the number of years that the CEO appears as an executive for the firm in
Execucomp. We determine whether the CEO became an executive or board member in
the acquiring firm by reading press releases surrounding the offer, and by
reading the next proxy statement of the acquirer after the close of the deal.
Hartzell
et al. (2004) document the importance of golden parachutes and special bonuses
in change in control compensation for CEOs. To that end, we harvest the golden
parachute multiple for each target CEO from the last proxy statement prior to
the announcement of the deal. By definition, the golden parachute multiple is
the number of years of salary plus bonus paid as severance upon termination
following a change in control. We find a golden parachute multiple for 97% of
our CEOs.9 We also read all of the 8-k filings after the deal is
announced to learn about augmentation of the golden parachute and special
bonuses.
We
include board characteristics to capture the quality of governance of the
target firm. We define board members as independent if they are not current or
former employees of the firm, family members of current or former employees, or
providing services to the firm. We define board members as busy if they serve
on three or more boards in total including the board of the target. We
determine the independence and busyness of each board member, as well as CEO
duality, by reading the proxy statement immediately preceding the takeover.
Most
variables describing the deal characteristics were hand collected. We determine
if each deal was a tender offer by reading the SEC filings. We also measure the
percentage of the offer price that is paid in cash. Huang and Walkling (1987)
and Fich et al. (2011) report higher acquisition premia for cash and for tender
offers. Furthermore, the merger background in the proxy statement provides
information regarding whether the target was looking to be acquired. If it
appears that the target wanted to be acquired, we assume that the target
solicited the bidder, and assign a value of one to the indicator variable we
call Solicited. If it appears
that the negotiations were mutual from the beginning and there is no evidence
of which party initiated the transaction, we assume the bidder initiated the
offer and assign a value of zero. Following Boone and Mulherin (2007), we read
the merger backgrounds to determine if there were multiple bids for the target.
Presumably the premium will be higher if there is more than one bidder. To
proxy for synergies, we use the acquirers stock return. The acquirers
announcement period cumulative abnormal return (CAR) is calculated using the
market model over the window from one day before to one day after the
announcement. We would have included a deal hostility indicator in our data if
a sufficient portion of the acquisitions had been hostile. However, only two of
the 107 deals are hostile, which is not enough from which to make meaningful
inferences.10 A summary of all of our variables is presented in
Table I.
9
Hartzell et al. (2004) find that 69% of their CEOs receive a golden
parachute. Presumably, the difference is due to better disclosure rules since
the end of their sample in 1997.
10
We follow Morck, Shleifer, and Vishny (1988) in classifying a deal as
hostile if it was not negotiated prior to the initial bid, was not accepted by
the board from the start, or was contested by target management in anyway. We
learn this information from SEC filings and LexisNexis.
|
|
8
|
Financial Management XXX 2012
|
|
Table I. Description of Variables
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Variable
|
|
Description
|
|
Source
|
|
|
|
|
|
Offer Qualities
|
|
|
|
|
Market Model premium
|
|
Acquisition premium calculated as in Schwert (1996) using the market
model over the window [40, close].
|
|
CRSP
|
Fama-French premium
|
|
Acquisition premium calculated as in Schwert (1996) using the
Fama-French (1993) three-factor model over the window [40, close].
|
|
CRSP
|
Tender offer
|
|
An indicator variable set equal to one if the target is acquired via
tender offer, and zero otherwise.
|
|
Edgar
|
Cash as a % of offer
|
|
The percentage of the total offer price for the target that is paid in
cash.
|
|
Edgar
|
Relative size
|
|
The size of the target divided by the size of the acquirer, as
measured by sales.
|
|
Compustat
|
Solicited
|
|
An indicator variable set equal to one if the target solicits itself
for sale, and zero otherwise.
|
|
Edgar
|
Acquirers CAR (%)
|
|
Cumulative announcement period return for the acquirer for days [1,
1].
|
|
CRSP
|
Multiple bids
|
|
An indicator variable set equal to one if the target received multiple
bids, and zero otherwise.
|
|
Edgar
|
CEO Qualities
|
|
|
|
|
Accelerated (0,1)
|
|
An indicator variable that takes a value of one if the CEO of the
target firm receives accelerated vesting of his equity grants at the close of
the acquisition, and zero otherwise.
|
|
Edgar
|
CEO age
|
|
The age of the targets CEO as of the last proxy statement before the
acquisition or, if new, the press release announcing the hiring of CEO.
|
|
Execucomp, Edgar
|
CEO tenure
|
|
The number of years that the CEO has been a named executive with the
target firm.
|
|
Execucomp, Edgar
|
CEO offer
|
|
An indicator variable set equal to one if the targets CEO is offered
a job with the acquiring firm, and zero otherwise.
|
|
Edgar, Lexis Nexis
|
CEO ownership
|
|
The dollar value of shares of common stock held by the CEO plus the
dollar value of unexercised options all divided by TDC2 (as defined below).
|
|
Execucomp, Compustat
|
Financials
|
|
|
|
|
Cash/Sales
|
|
The ratio of cash (Compustat item CHE) to sales (SALE) as of the end
of the fiscal year immediately preceding the acquisition.
|
|
Compustat
|
Ln(Sales)
|
|
The natural log of sales (SALE) as of the end of the fiscal year
immediately preceding the acquisition.
|
|
Compustat
|
Market value of assets
|
|
Debt (DLTT+DLC) plus common stock (PRCCF*CSHO) plus preferred stock
(PSTKL) minus deferred taxes (TXDC) and investment tax credits (ITCI).
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(Continued)
|
|
Elkinawy & Offenberg Accelerated Vesting
in Takeovers
|
9
|
|
Table I. Description of Variables (Continued)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Variable
|
|
Description
|
|
Source
|
|
|
|
|
|
LT Debt/Assets
|
|
The ratio of long-term debt (DLTT) to the market value of assets (see
above) as of the end of the fiscal year immediately preceding the
acquisition.
|
|
Compustat
|
Market/Book
|
|
The market value of assets (see above) divided by the book value of
assets (AT).
|
|
Compustat
|
Return on equity
|
|
The net income in year t divided
by the market value of equity in year t-1.
|
|
Compustat
|
Board Qualities
|
|
|
|
|
CEO duality
|
|
An indicator variable set equal to one if the CEO is also Chairman of
the board, and zero otherwise.
|
|
Execucomp, Edgar
|
Board outsiders (%)
|
|
The percentage of the board of directors that is independent.
|
|
Edgar
|
Busy board (%)
|
|
The percentage of the board of directors that sits on three or more
boards.
|
|
Edgar
|
CEO Compensation
|
|
|
|
|
GP multiple
|
|
Number of years of Salary plus Bonus paid as a golden parachute to the
CEO upon termination following a change in control.
|
|
Edgar
|
GP increase
|
|
An indicator variable set equal to one if the CEOs golden parachute
was increased after the deal was signed, and zero otherwise.
|
|
Edgar
|
New bonus
|
|
An indicator variable set equal to one if the CEO was offered
additional compensation after the deal was signed, and zero otherwise.
|
|
Edgar
|
Salary
|
|
CEOs cash salary.
|
|
Execucomp
|
Bonus
|
|
CEOs cash bonus.
|
|
Execucomp
|
TDC1
|
|
Total dollar value of CEO compensation including the value of option
grants, as recorded by Execucomp.
|
|
Execucomp
|
TDC2
|
|
Total dollar value of CEO compensation including the value of options
exercised, as recorded by Execucomp.
|
|
Execucomp
|
Res. stock ownership
|
|
The market value of the restricted stock held by the CEO (Execucomp
variable: Stock_Unvest_Val).
|
|
Execucomp
|
Unvested options
|
|
The exercise value of all unvested options held by the CEO (Execucomp
variable: Opt_Unex_Unexer_Est_Val).
|
|
Execucomp
|
Unvested ownership
|
|
The dollar value of restricted stock and unvested stock options held
by the CEO.
|
|
Execucomp
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
10
|
Financial Management XXX 2012
|
|
Table II. Sample Summary
This table reports a summary
of the sample of firms that were acquired from 2005 to 2009. Panel A presents
firm counts by year. The column labeled Accelerated includes firms for which
the CEOs vesting on stock and options accelerates at the close of the deal.
Panel B provides firm counts by industry, where firms are grouped into the 12
Fama-French (1997) industries.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Panel A. Observation Counts by Year |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Year |
|
All |
|
Accelerated |
|
Nonaccelerated |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
N |
|
% |
|
N |
|
% |
|
N |
|
% |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
2005 |
|
34 |
|
32% |
|
21 |
|
26% |
|
13 |
|
48% |
|
2006 |
|
21 |
|
20% |
|
17 |
|
21% |
|
4 |
|
15% |
|
2007 |
|
32 |
|
30% |
|
25 |
|
31% |
|
7 |
|
26% |
|
2008 |
|
15 |
|
14% |
|
14 |
|
18% |
|
1 |
|
4% |
|
2009 |
|
5 |
|
5% |
|
3 |
|
4% |
|
2 |
|
7% |
|
Total |
|
107 |
|
100% |
|
80 |
|
100% |
|
27 |
|
100% |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Panel B. Observation
Counts by Industry |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Industry |
|
All |
|
Accelerated |
|
Nonaccelerated |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
N |
|
% |
|
N |
|
% |
|
N |
|
% |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Consumer
nondurables |
|
6 |
|
6% |
|
4 |
|
5% |
|
2 |
|
7% |
|
Consumer
durables |
|
2 |
|
2% |
|
2 |
|
3% |
|
0 |
|
0% |
|
Manufacturing |
|
12 |
|
11% |
|
9 |
|
11% |
|
3 |
|
11% |
|
Oil,
gas, and coal extraction and products |
|
6 |
|
6% |
|
4 |
|
5% |
|
2 |
|
7% |
|
Chemicals
and allied products |
|
2 |
|
2% |
|
2 |
|
3% |
|
0 |
|
0% |
|
Business
equipment |
|
14 |
|
13% |
|
11 |
|
14% |
|
3 |
|
11% |
|
Telephone
and television transmission |
|
6 |
|
6% |
|
3 |
|
4% |
|
3 |
|
11% |
|
Wholesale,
retail, and some services |
|
13 |
|
12% |
|
11 |
|
14% |
|
2 |
|
7% |
|
Healthcare,
medical
equipment, and drugs |
|
20 |
|
19% |
|
17 |
|
21% |
|
3 |
|
11% |
|
Other |
|
26 |
|
24% |
|
17 |
|
21% |
|
9 |
|
33% |
|
Total |
|
107 |
|
100% |
|
80 |
|
100% |
|
27 |
|
100% |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
III.
Results
Summary
statistics for the sample are presented in Table II. Panel A of Table II
reports how the sample is split by year. As expected, a majority of the deals
happen before the financial crisis. Fifty-five deals, or about half the sample,
occur in 2005 and 2006. The sample tapers off notably, with only five deals in
2009. While this seems like a data error at first glance, it is, in fact, correct.
It appears that acquisition markets seized up during the crisis.11 Panel
B of Table II presents the distribution of firms across industries. For this
panel, we group the companies in our sample into the 12 Fama-French (1997)
industry classifications. Note that the two industry
|
|
11 Our results do
not change significantly if we ignore deals that closed in 2008 and 2009.
|
|
|
Elkinawy & Offenberg Accelerated Vesting in Takeovers
|
11
|
|
groups
representing financials and utilities are excluded. We do have a wide
representation in each of the 10 industries.
|
A. Univariate Results
Table
III reports average and median values (in italics) for the sample as a whole,
and for the accelerated and nonaccelerated subsamples. The two subsamples are
similar in offer characteristics, board composition, market-to-book ratio,
sales, and assets. There are significant differences in the CEOs who serve
these firms. Accelerating firms have older and longer serving leaders than
nonaccelerating firms. The CEOs of accelerating firms are also more likely to
serve the dual role of Chairman and have larger golden parachutes. We control
for these differences in our regressions that explain the variation in takeover
premiums later in this paper.
In
the analysis that follows, we calculate premiums two different ways. In our
Market-Model Specification, we calculate the premium as a market model abnormal
return. In our Fama-French Specification, we adjust the returns over the same
time frame for the three Fama-French (1993) factors. Following Schwert (1996),
we estimate these two specifications of premiums from 40 trading days before the
announcement through the close of the deal. We use the Schwert (1996)
calculation as it alleviates the anticipation problem with event study returns
described in Offenberg and Officer (2010). It also has the benefit of including
the run-up in the stock price leading up to the announcement, the mark-up in
the stock price from the original offer, and all future revised offers.
Table
IV reports the differences in acquisition premiums for the firms with and
without accelerated vesting. When premiums are measured with the market model,
accelerated firms earn an average premium of 30.63%, whereas the premium for
nonaccelerated firms is about half at 15.35%. The difference is significant at
the 5% level. We arrive at similar results if we measure premiums with the
Fama-French (1993) three-factor model rather than the market model. These
findings present the first evidence that accelerated vesting of the CEOs
equity aligns their interests with those of their shareholders.
Further
evidence regarding the relationship between the acquisition premium and
accelerated vesting, as well as other key explanatory variables, is revealed by
the correlation matrix in Table V. This is a truncated correlation matrix. For
brevity, we only report the correlation coefficients of the three main
variables with all of the explanatory variables. In the first column, the
correlation between the two measures of acquisition premiums is reported to be
0.83, which is significant at the 1% level. As expected, our premiums are
highly correlated. The premiums are also positively correlated with tender
offers, but lower when the target solicits the bid. Building on the results in
Table IV, we also report a significantly positive correlation between the
presence of accelerated vesting provisions and the premium. In the third
column, we document a strong positive correlation between accelerated vesting
and the age and tenure of the CEO, as well as the size of their golden
parachutes.
Perhaps
what is most surprising about Table V is the lack of correlations. For
instance, we fail to find a relationship between accelerated vesting and the
CEO receiving a job with the acquirer. Hypothetically, if the CEO knew they
would not benefit from accelerated vesting, they would be motivated to
negotiate harder for a position with the buyer. Thus far, our results do not
support that theory. We also fail to find a correlation between accelerated
vesting and augmentations of golden parachutes or new bonuses. The CEOs who are
not getting rewarded with accelerated vesting are not getting rewarded in these
other ways either. Our results also indicate that there is no association
between accelerated vesting and the targets efforts to solicit a bid for
itself. In other words, CEOs, who would potentially receive the benefit of
accelerated vesting, are not
|
|
12
|
Financial Management XXX 2012
|
|
Table III. Summary Statistics
|
This
table reports summary statistics for a number of control variables as described
in Table I. The means are presented in the plain text, whereas medians are
reported in italics. The column labeled Accelerated includes firms for which
the CEOs vesting on stock and options accelerates at the close of the deal.
Differences of means between the accelerated and nonaccelerated groups are
measured with a t-test, whereas
differences of medians are measured with a Wilcoxson signed-rank test.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Variable |
|
All |
|
Accelerated |
|
Nonaccelerated |
|
Difference |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Offer
Qualities |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Tender
offer |
|
16.80% |
|
17.50% |
|
14.80% |
|
2.70% |
|
|
|
0.0% |
|
0.0% |
|
0.0% |
|
0.00% |
|
Cash
as a% of offer |
|
69.60% |
|
74.30% |
|
55.80% |
|
18.50%** |
|
|
|
100.0% |
|
100.0% |
|
55.0% |
|
45.00% |
|
Relative
size |
|
81.90% |
|
82.71% |
|
79.44% |
|
3.27% |
|
|
|
82.0% |
|
83.3% |
|
79.6% |
|
3.71% |
|
Solicited |
|
28.97% |
|
30.00% |
|
25.92% |
|
4.08% |
|
|
|
0.0% |
|
0.0% |
|
0.0% |
|
0.00% |
|
Acquirers
CAR (%) |
|
-2.19% |
|
-1.72% |
|
-3.67% |
|
1.95%* |
|
|
|
-1.56% |
|
-1.12% |
|
-1.71% |
|
0.59% |
|
Multiple
bids |
|
21.50% |
|
21.25% |
|
22.22% |
|
-0.97% |
|
|
|
0.00% |
|
0.00% |
|
0.00% |
|
0.00% |
|
CEO
Qualities |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
CEO
age |
|
54.64 |
|
55.66 |
|
51.59 |
|
4.07*** |
|
|
|
54 |
|
56 |
|
51 |
|
5*** |
|
CEO
tenure |
|
6.51 |
|
7.04 |
|
4.96 |
|
2.07*** |
|
|
|
6 |
|
7.50 |
|
4 |
|
3.5*** |
|
GP
multiple |
|
2.41 |
|
2.55 |
|
2.00 |
|
0.55*** |
|
|
|
2.99 |
|
3.00 |
|
2.00 |
|
1.00** |
|
GP
increase |
|
4.67% |
|
3.75% |
|
7.41% |
|
-3.66% |
|
|
|
0.0% |
|
0.0% |
|
0.0% |
|
0.00% |
|
New
bonus |
|
28.97% |
|
28.75% |
|
29.63% |
|
-0.88% |
|
|
|
0.0% |
|
0.0% |
|
0.0% |
|
0.00% |
|
CEO
offer |
|
21.50% |
|
18.75% |
|
29.63% |
|
-10.88% |
|
|
|
0.0% |
|
0.0% |
|
0.0% |
|
0.00% |
|
CEO
ownership |
|
7.44 |
|
7.56 |
|
7.10 |
|
0.46 |
|
|
|
3.05 |
|
3.91 |
|
1.46 |
|
2.45* |
|
Board
Qualities |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
CEO
duality |
|
67.28% |
|
71.25% |
|
55.56% |
|
15.69%* |
|
|
|
100.0% |
|
100.0% |
|
100.0% |
|
0.00% |
|
Board
outsiders (%) |
|
78.16% |
|
78.90% |
|
76.09% |
|
2.81% |
|
|
|
80.0% |
|
83.3% |
|
80.0% |
|
3.33% |
|
Busy
board (%) |
|
33.70% |
|
32.86% |
|
36.22% |
|
-3.36% |
|
|
|
33.3% |
|
33.3% |
|
37.5% |
|
-4.17% |
|
Target
Financials |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Sales
($ billions) |
|
3.4 |
|
3.69 |
|
2.53 |
|
1.17 |
|
|
|
0.778 |
|
1.00 |
|
0.436 |
|
0.564 |
|
Assets
(book) |
|
3.65 |
|
3.79 |
|
3.23 |
|
0.55 |
|
|
|
0.825 |
|
0.931 |
|
0.669 |
|
0.262 |
|
Cash/Sales |
|
0.503 |
|
0.553 |
|
0.355 |
|
0.197 |
|
|
|
0.144 |
|
0.116 |
|
0.233 |
|
-0.117** |
|
LT
Debt/Assets |
|
12.87% |
|
13.85% |
|
9.97% |
|
3.88% |
|
|
|
7.35% |
|
8.79% |
|
0.003% |
|
8.79%* |
|
Market/Book |
|
1.87 |
|
1.89 |
|
1.82 |
|
0.07 |
|
|
|
1.60 |
|
1.59 |
|
1.65 |
|
-0.06 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
***Significant at the 0.01 level. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
**Significant at the 0.05 level. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
*Significant at the 0.10 level. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Elkinawy & Offenberg Accelerated Vesting in Takeovers
|
13
|
|
Table IV. t-Tests for Differences of Premiums
|
This
table reports the averages and differences in premiums. Premiums are measured
from 40 days prior to the announcement to the close of the deal. Firms are
assigned to the Accelerated Vesting column if the firms CEO receives
accelerated vesting of restricted stock or stock options upon the close of the
deal.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Accelerated
Vesting |
|
Nonaccelerated
Vesting |
|
Difference |
|
p-Value
for
Difference |
|
n |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Market
Model premiums |
|
30.63% |
|
15.35% |
|
15.28% |
|
0.0117 |
|
107 |
|
Fama-French
premiums |
|
27.17% |
|
15.35% |
|
11.82% |
|
0.0291 |
|
107 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Table V. Correlation Matrix
This
table presents a truncated correlation matrix for the variables used in this
study. Only three columns of the matrix are shown. Accelerated (0,1) is an indicator variable that takes a
value of one if the CEO of the target firm receives accelerated vesting of his
equity grants at the close of the acquisition, and zero otherwise. All
variables are described in Table I.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Market
Model
premiums |
Fama-French
premiums |
Accelerated
(0,1) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Offer
Qualities |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Fama-French
premiums |
|
|
0.830 |
*** |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Tender
offer |
|
|
0.270 |
*** |
|
0.290 |
*** |
|
0.030 |
|
Cash
as a% of offer |
|
|
0.130 |
|
|
0.300 |
*** |
|
0.210 |
** |
Relative
size |
|
|
-0.103 |
|
|
-0.171 |
* |
|
0.078 |
|
Solicited |
|
|
-0.214 |
** |
|
-0.215 |
** |
|
0.039 |
|
Acquirers
CAR (%) |
|
|
0.125 |
|
|
0.117 |
|
|
0.129 |
|
Multiple
bids |
|
|
0.202 |
** |
|
0.242 |
** |
|
-0.010 |
|
CEO
Qualities |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Accelerated
(0,1) |
|
|
0.220 |
** |
|
0.180 |
* |
|
1.000 |
|
CEO
age |
|
|
0.000 |
|
|
-0.060 |
|
|
0.280 |
*** |
CEO
tenure |
|
|
0.000 |
|
|
-0.020 |
|
|
0.250 |
*** |
CEO
offer |
|
|
0.050 |
|
|
-0.030 |
|
|
-0.120 |
|
CEO
ownership |
|
|
0.172 |
* |
|
0.165 |
* |
|
0.014 |
|
GP
multiple |
|
|
-0.116 |
|
|
-0.153 |
|
|
0.281 |
*** |
GP
increase |
|
|
0.000 |
|
|
0.026 |
|
|
-0.075 |
|
New
bonus |
|
|
0.166 |
* |
|
0.189 |
|
|
-0.008 |
|
Board
Qualities |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
CEO
duality |
|
|
-0.080 |
|
|
-0.120 |
|
|
0.150 |
|
Board
outsiders (%) |
|
|
0.040 |
|
|
0.010 |
|
|
0.110 |
|
Busy
board (%) |
|
|
-0.020 |
|
|
-0.020 |
|
|
-0.070 |
|
Target
Financials |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Cash/Sales |
|
|
0.150 |
|
|
0.130 |
|
|
0.040 |
|
Ln(Sales) |
|
|
-0.050 |
|
|
-0.020 |
|
|
0.110 |
|
LT
Debt/Assets |
|
|
0.100 |
|
|
0.090 |
|
|
0.120 |
|
Market/Book |
|
|
-0.120 |
|
|
-0.130 |
|
|
0.030 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
***Significant at the 0.01 level. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
**Significant at the 0.05 level. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
*Significant at the 0.10 level. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
14
|
Financial Management XXX 2012
|
|
putting
forth more effort to sell the firm than CEOs who do not get accelerated
vesting. While we expect to learn more about these relationships in the
regression analysis that follows, the univariate statistics are compelling.
B. Regression Analysis
We
begin our multivariate analysis with ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions
that model the takeover premium against the accelerated vesting dummy variable
and control for the characteristics of the CEO, the deal, the targets board,
and the targets financials in addition to the year and industry fixed effects.
The fixed effects are included to account for differences in premiums between
industries and between years during this volatile time in the markets. The goal
of these regressions is to test whether accelerated vesting is still a
significant predictor of the takeover premium, even after controlling for other
explanatory variables. Our regression model is as follows:
|
|
|
Premium =
|
a + ß1 (Accelerated
Vesting dummy) + ßW (CEO
qualities)
|
|
|
|
|
|
+ ßX (Offer qualities) + ßY
(Board qualities) + ßZ
(Target financials).
|
(1)
|
The
results of these regressions are presented in Table VI. In the first
regression, we exclude two types of variables: 1) those that are potentially
endogenous (CEO Offer), and 2) those that are censored by a lack of data
(acquirers CAR and relative size). This gives us a clean test with all 107
observations and most of our explanatory variables. Even after accounting for
all of the other factors that may impact the premium, the accelerated vesting
dummy variable in the first model carries a coefficient of 0.158, and is statistically
significant at the 5% level. This is our main result, as it documents a
significant, positive correlation between the presence of accelerated vesting
provisions and takeover premiums. This result supports the Incentive Alignment
Hypothesis, implying that accelerated vesting provisions give target managers
the proper incentive to maximize shareholder wealth, thereby reducing agency
costs in a takeover.
The
positive correlation between accelerated vesting and premiums is further supported
by the results in the second column, which replaces the market model premium
with the Fama-French (1993) premium. The size and significance of the
coefficient on the accelerated vesting dummy variable changes little in this
second model. In the third and fourth columns, we add in the dummy variable
indicating that the CEO accepted a job offer from the acquirer, as well as the
acquirers CAR and relative size. In the process, 12 observations are lost,
representing the firms that were acquired by private buyers. Once again, our
results are unchanged.
There
are two potential endogeneity issues that may be skewing our results. First, it
is possible that firms put accelerated vesting provisions in place because they
expect to be the target of a takeover with a large premium in the near future.
If that is the case, then our accelerated vesting dummy is merely proxying for
managements expectations of a lucrative takeover rather than proxying for
managements incentive alignment. In order to rule out the possibility that
accelerated vesting provisions are simply well timed, we need to demonstrate
that such provisions were put in place before management could estimate the
takeover premium. Given that Harford (2005) finds that merger waves last about
two years, we argue that any provision enacted three years before the deal
could not have been motivated by the expectation of a high takeover premium.
Therefore, we exclude all firms that enacted accelerated vesting provisions
within three years of the announcement date of the takeover.12 By
excluding firms with newer accelerated vesting
|
12 We read
through the relevant documents on EDGAR to determine the age of the
accelerated vesting provisions.
|
|
|
Elkinawy
& Offenberg Accelerated Vesting in
Takeovers
|
15
|
|
|
Table
VI. Determinants of Takeover Premiums
This
table provides the coefficient estimates from OLS regressions. The dependent
variable is the acquisition premium. The independent variables are described in
Table I. Fixed effects are by year and Fama-French (1997) 48 industries. Robust
standard errors are used to calculate p-values
(shown in parentheses). Models 5 and 6 only include firms that had accelerated
vesting provisions in place for at least three years.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(1)
Market
Model
Premiums |
(2)
Fama-
French
Premiums |
(3)
Market
Model
Premiums |
(4)
Fama-
French
Premiums |
(5)
Market
Model
Premiums |
(6)
Fama-
French
Premiums |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Accelerated
(0,1) |
|
0.158 |
|
|
0.131 |
|
|
0.176 |
|
|
0.173 |
|
|
0.194 |
|
|
0.162 |
|
|
|
(0.026 |
) |
|
(0.092 |
) |
|
(0.016 |
) |
|
(0.029 |
) |
|
(0.001 |
) |
|
0.000 |
|
CEO age |
|
0.001 |
|
|
-0.002 |
|
|
-0.002 |
|
|
-0.002 |
|
|
0.000 |
|
|
-0.001 |
|
|
|
(0.838 |
) |
|
(0.659 |
) |
|
(0.539 |
) |
|
(0.700 |
) |
|
(0.898 |
) |
|
(0.783 |
) |
CEO tenure |
|
0.018 |
|
|
0.004 |
|
|
0.016 |
|
|
-0.002 |
|
|
0.007 |
|
|
-0.006 |
|
|
|
(0.278 |
) |
|
(0.684 |
) |
|
(0.394 |
) |
|
(0.842 |
) |
|
(0.524 |
) |
|
(0.468 |
) |
GP multiple |
|
-0.045 |
|
|
-0.049 |
|
|
-0.026 |
|
|
-0.026 |
|
|
-0.023 |
|
|
-0.042 |
|
|
|
(0.143 |
) |
|
(0.194 |
) |
|
(0.443 |
) |
|
(0.553 |
) |
|
(0.590 |
) |
|
(0.385 |
) |
GP increase |
|
-0.111 |
|
|
-0.010 |
|
|
-0.214 |
|
|
-0.185 |
|
|
-0.411 |
|
|
0.132 |
|
|
|
(0.364 |
) |
|
(0.949 |
) |
|
(0.149 |
) |
|
(0.276 |
) |
|
(0.292 |
) |
|
(0.365 |
) |
New bonus |
|
0.126 |
|
|
0.138 |
|
|
0.110 |
|
|
0.13 |
|
|
0.083 |
|
|
0.118 |
|
|
|
(0.093 |
) |
|
(0.068 |
) |
|
(0.082 |
) |
|
(0.019 |
) |
|
(0.275 |
) |
|
(0.111 |
) |
CEO offer |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.100 |
|
|
0.111 |
|
|
0.111 |
|
|
0.110 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.275 |
) |
|
(0.174 |
) |
|
(0.121 |
) |
|
(0.112 |
) |
CEO
ownership |
|
0.003 |
|
|
0.002 |
|
|
0.003 |
|
|
0.003 |
|
|
0.003 |
|
|
0.003 |
|
|
|
(0.080 |
) |
|
(0.173 |
) |
|
(0.141 |
) |
|
(0.134 |
) |
|
(0.154 |
) |
|
(0.198 |
) |
Tender |
|
0.278 |
|
|
0.192 |
|
|
0.298 |
|
|
0.224 |
|
|
0.155 |
|
|
0.081 |
|
|
|
(0.000 |
) |
|
(0.035 |
) |
|
(0.002 |
) |
|
(0.031 |
) |
|
(0.201 |
) |
|
(0.395 |
) |
Cash as a %
of offer |
|
-0.059 |
|
|
0.068 |
|
|
-0.010 |
|
|
0.101 |
|
|
-0.007 |
|
|
0.102 |
|
|
|
(0.466 |
) |
|
(0.352 |
) |
|
(0.923 |
) |
|
(0.239 |
) |
|
(0.951 |
) |
|
(0.169 |
) |
Solicited |
|
-0.127 |
|
|
-0.071 |
|
|
-0.173 |
|
|
-0.11 |
|
|
-0.209 |
|
|
-0.142 |
|
|
|
(0.032 |
) |
|
(0.245 |
) |
|
(0.005 |
) |
|
(0.068 |
) |
|
(0.012 |
) |
|
(0.131 |
) |
Relative
size |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.362 |
|
|
0.066 |
|
|
0.377 |
|
|
0.136 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.176 |
) |
|
(0.763 |
) |
|
(0.252 |
) |
|
(0.617 |
) |
Acquirers
CAR (%) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.395 |
|
|
-0.413 |
|
|
0.290 |
|
|
-0.459 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.632 |
) |
|
(0.411 |
) |
|
(0.722 |
) |
|
(0.518 |
) |
Multiple
bids |
|
0.108 |
|
|
0.115 |
|
|
0.086 |
|
|
0.066 |
|
|
-0.012 |
|
|
-0.045 |
|
|
|
(0.046 |
) |
|
(0.154 |
) |
|
(0.130 |
) |
|
(0.401 |
) |
|
(0.875 |
) |
|
(0.596 |
) |
CEO duality |
|
-0.047 |
|
|
-0.026 |
|
|
-0.033 |
|
|
-0.016 |
|
|
0.024 |
|
|
0.043 |
|
|
|
(0.240 |
) |
|
(0.605 |
) |
|
(0.237 |
) |
|
(0.763 |
) |
|
(0.590 |
) |
|
(0.368 |
) |
Board
outsiders (%) |
|
-0.158 |
|
|
-0.284 |
|
|
-0.111 |
|
|
-0.231 |
|
|
-0.287 |
|
|
-0.416 |
|
|
|
(0.623 |
) |
|
(0.346 |
) |
|
(0.794 |
) |
|
(0.477 |
) |
|
(0.515 |
) |
|
(0.289 |
) |
Busy board
(%) |
|
-0.196 |
|
|
-0.201 |
|
|
-0.102 |
|
|
-0.106 |
|
|
-0.011 |
|
|
-0.069 |
|
|
|
(0.218 |
) |
|
(0.202 |
) |
|
(0.369 |
) |
|
(0.426 |
) |
|
(0.944 |
) |
|
(0.674 |
) |
Cash/Sales |
|
0.024 |
|
|
0.015 |
|
|
0.024 |
|
|
0.012 |
|
|
0.139 |
|
|
0.164 |
|
|
|
(0.053 |
) |
|
(0.124 |
) |
|
(0.090 |
) |
|
(0.329 |
) |
|
(0.112 |
) |
|
(0.197 |
) |
Ln(Sales) |
|
-0.025 |
|
|
0.007 |
|
|
-0.061 |
|
|
-0.004 |
|
|
-0.102 |
|
|
-0.020 |
|
|
|
(0.338 |
) |
|
(0.718 |
) |
|
(0.088 |
) |
|
(0.892 |
) |
|
(0.075 |
) |
|
(0.599 |
) |
LT
Debt/Assets |
|
0.309 |
|
|
0.382 |
|
|
0.332 |
|
|
0.645 |
|
|
1.066 |
|
|
0.909 |
|
|
|
(0.318 |
) |
|
(0.225 |
) |
|
(0.380 |
) |
|
(0.099 |
) |
|
(0.045 |
) |
|
(0.043 |
) |
Market/Book |
|
-0.013 |
|
|
-0.019 |
|
|
-0.011 |
|
|
-0.003 |
|
|
-0.015 |
|
|
-0.041 |
|
|
|
(0.563 |
) |
|
(0.360 |
) |
|
(0.805 |
) |
|
(0.949 |
) |
|
(0.704 |
) |
|
(0.325 |
) |
Constant |
|
0.412 |
|
|
0.426 |
|
|
0.339 |
|
|
0.196 |
|
|
0.416 |
|
|
0.365 |
|
|
|
(0.110 |
) |
|
(0.093 |
) |
|
(0.284 |
) |
|
(0.552 |
) |
|
(0.417 |
) |
|
(0.441 |
) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Year dummies |
|
yes |
|
|
yes |
|
|
yes |
|
|
yes |
|
|
yes |
|
|
yes |
|
Industry
dummies |
|
yes |
|
|
yes |
|
|
yes |
|
|
yes |
|
|
yes |
|
|
yes |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Observations |
|
107 |
|
|
107 |
|
|
95 |
|
|
95 |
|
|
74 |
|
|
74 |
|
Adjusted R2 |
|
0.361 |
|
|
0.353 |
|
|
0.395 |
|
|
0.377 |
|
|
0.514 |
|
|
0.465 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
16
|
Financial
Management XXX 2012
|
|
|
|
contracts,
we lose 33 observations. Our results are reported in Columns 5 and 6 of Table
VI. The coefficient on the accelerated vesting dummy is still significantly
positive. It appears that our original results are not influenced by this
endogeneity issue.
|
As
noted previously, the targets CEO may take actions in the merger
negotiations to protect their future. For instance, the CEO may make
trade-offs between the premium and a job offer with the acquirer. Therefore,
the premium and whether the CEO takes a position with the acquirer may be
endogenous. To study this possibility, we test the robustness of the models
in Columns 3 and 4 of Table VI with a two-stage probit as in Maddala (1983)
to control for the CEOs simultaneous decisions to negotiate for a premium
and accept an offer with the acquirer. In the first stage, a probit model
sets the CEO Offer dummy as the dependent variable and uses the CEOs age,
tenure, stock ownership, golden parachute multiplier, and duality as the
independent variables. The estimated probability of the CEO receiving an
offer from the first stage then becomes an explanatory variable in the second
stage. The OLS model used in the second stage sets the premium as the
left-hand side variable and also uses the accelerated vesting dummy with the
deal characteristics, firm characteristics, and board characteristics from
Column 1 of Table VI as additional explanatory variables. In untabulated
results, we find that the coefficient on the accelerated vesting dummy is
still positive and significant at the 5% level, regardless of which measure
of premium we use. Our results in Columns 3 and 4 of Table VI are robust to
controls for this second endogeneity issue. The data suggest that the
takeover premium is not affected by the CEOs future employment with the
acquirer. Our key result still holds that accelerated vesting aligns the
incentives of the manager with those of the shareholder.
|
|
C. Robustness
|
|
While
our results thus far suggest that accelerated vesting provisions are
beneficial to stock holders, it is not clear whether some selection bias is
at play. More specifically, it could be the case that firms enact accelerated
vesting provisions when they think they are likely to be taken over. To help
test for this possibility, we build a matching sample of firms that are not
acquired from 2005 to 2009. These matching firms are important to our
analysis precisely because they have not been taken over. Therefore, they
offer us a glimpse of how the rest of the executive compensation market
behaves with respect to accelerated vesting.
|
As
in Rosenbaum and Rubin (1983), we use propensity score matching to control
for a possible selection bias. In our case, the propensity score measures the
probability that a firm is taken over. If firms enact accelerated vesting
provisions when they are more likely to be taken over, then we should observe
a higher rate of accelerated vesting in firms with higher propensity scores.
Therefore, using a propensity score matched sample should allow us to
determine if accelerated vesting is put in place in preparation for a
takeover or if it is a common clause in executive compensation contracts.
|
To
build the matching sample, we initially calculate the probability of each
firm being acquired based on a series of financial and CEO characteristics.
To do so, we estimate a probit model as follows:
|
|
|
Pr(Acquired)
= a + ß1(CEO tenure) + ß2(CEO Ownership) + ß3(Sales) + ß4(M/B)
|
|
|
|
+
ß5(ROE) + ß6(Cash/Sales) + ß7(Debt/Assets).
|
(2)
|
The
control variables for this model come from a long literature that attempts to
predict takeover likelihood, from Palepu (1986) through Offenberg (2009). Our
probit model also contains year and industry fixed effects. This probit model
is estimated for all firm-years in Execucomp from
|
|
Elkinawy
& Offenberg Accelerated Vesting in
Takeovers
|
17
|
|
|
Table
VII. Probit Model to Predict Takeover Targets for Propensity Score
Matching
This
table reports the coefficient estimates from the probit regression that
generated the propensity score used to build the matching sample of nonacquired
firms. The dependent variable is an indicator set to one if the firm is
acquired and zero otherwise (the matching sample). The independent variables
are described in Table I. Fixed effects are by year and Fama-French (1997) 48
industries. Robust standard errors are used to calculate p-values (shown in parentheses).
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Dependent
Variable = Pr(acquired) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
CEO tenure |
|
|
-0.114 |
|
|
|
|
(0.000 |
) |
CEO ownership |
|
|
-0.597 |
|
|
|
|
(0.000 |
) |
Ln(Sales) |
|
|
-0.148 |
|
|
|
|
0.058 |
|
Market/Book |
|
|
-0.052 |
|
|
|
|
(0.515 |
) |
Return on equity |
|
|
2.748 |
|
|
|
|
(0.000 |
) |
Cash/Sales |
|
|
-0.036 |
|
|
|
|
(0.383 |
) |
LT Debt/Assets |
|
|
0.285 |
|
|
|
|
(0.737 |
) |
Constant |
|
|
4.642 |
|
|
|
|
(0.001 |
) |
|
|
|
|
|
Year dummies |
|
|
yes |
|
Industry dummies |
|
|
yes |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Observations |
|
|
3723 |
|
Pseudo-R2 |
|
|
0.263 |
|
Wald Chi2 |
|
|
264.92 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
2005
to 2009, including both acquired firms and nonacquired firms. The coefficient
estimates from our probit model are presented in Table VII.
|
The
next step in building the matching sample is to use the coefficients from the
probit model to estimate the propensity score for each firm in each year. We
then match each acquired firm to the nonacquired firm-year with the nearest
propensity score without replacement of the firm. Through this process, we
are able to find reasonable matches for 91 of the 107 firms in our main
sample. In unreported tests, we reestimate the main regressions in Table VI
for these 91 target firms, and find that the results are qualitatively
similar. Accelerated vesting provisions occur in 79% (72 of 91) of these
target firms. In other words, the subsample of targets with good matches appears
to be representative of the entire sample.
|
To
determine if the propensity score matching created statistically similar
samples, we compare the 91 target firms with their matched pairs across
variables that were not used in the regression in Table VII. The variables
that we consider include the age of the CEO, the book value of assets
(Compustat variable AT), operating cash flow (OIBDP-TXT), the ratio of
research and development expenses to assets (XRD/AT), capital expenditures to
assets (CAPX/AT), and the current ratio (ACT/LCT). Each of these variables
was chosen because they are common indicators of financial or operational
fitness and they are distinctly different from the variables employed in
|
|
|
18
|
Financial Management XXX 2012
|
|
|
Table VIII. Comparison of Matched Samples
|
This
table compares average values for target firms and a matching sample across a
number of variables, as described in Table I. Targets are matched to
nonacquired firms using propensity score matching. None of the differences of
means between the groups in Panel A are statistically significant. Only 91 of
the 107 acquired firms are used in this sample because good matches are not
available for the other 16. In Panel B, the percentages in italics represent
the proportion of the sample in each index. In Panel C, firms are split by
their propensity scores into Higher Probability and Lower Probability
subsamples around the median propensity score.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Panel A. Population Means |
|
Variable |
Targets |
Matching Firms |
Difference |
|
|
|
|
Accelerated |
79 |
% |
75 |
% |
4% |
|
CEO age |
54.91 |
|
54.6 |
|
0.31 |
|
Assets (book, Ln) |
7.18 |
|
7.29 |
|
-0.11 |
|
R&D/Assets |
6.13 |
% |
5.51 |
% |
0.62 |
% |
CapEx/Assets |
4.81 |
% |
4.60 |
% |
0.21 |
% |
Current ratio |
2.48 |
|
2.56 |
|
-0.08 |
|
Operating cash flow (Ln) |
4.96 |
|
5.1 |
|
-0.14 |
|
N |
91 |
|
91 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Panel B. Index Distribution |
|
Index |
Targets |
Matching Firms |
|
|
|
S & P 500 |
24 |
|
25 |
|
|
26 |
% |
27 |
% |
S & P Midcap 400 |
15 |
|
24 |
|
|
16 |
% |
26 |
% |
S & P Smallcap 600 |
44 |
|
35 |
|
|
48 |
% |
38 |
% |
None |
8 |
|
7 |
|
|
9 |
% |
8 |
% |
|
|
|
|
|
Total |
91 |
|
91 |
|
|
100 |
% |
100 |
% |
|
|
|
|
|
Panel C. Accelerated Vesting in Subsamples |
|
|
Targets |
Matching Firms |
All |
|
|
|
|
Higher probability |
72% |
64% |
68% |
Lower probability |
87% |
85% |
86% |
Difference |
15% |
21% |
18% |
p-value
for difference |
0.0815 |
0.0256 |
0.0047 |
|
|
|
|
the
logit model. We use a t-test to determine if there is a difference of means
between the target and matching samples. The results are presented in Panel A
of Table VIII. Note that there is no statistical difference between the two
samples among any of these variables. The propensity score matching harmonizes
well on variables that were not part of the original probit model. Our two
samples are remarkably similar across both the variables used in the logit and
these new variables introduced for robustness.
|
|
Elkinawy & Offenberg Accelerated Vesting in Takeovers
|
19
|
|
|
Of
course, the variable of interest in Panel A is the accelerated vesting
indicator. We find that 68 of our 91 matching companies (75%) provide their
CEOs with accelerated vesting. The difference in proportions between the two
samples is insignificant with both a one-tailed test and a two-tailed test. In
other words, CEOs of target firms are not significantly more likely to benefit
from accelerated vesting than CEOs of the matched sample.
To
offer a little more richness to our matching sample, we also include a
breakdown of the firms into their S&P indices in Panel B of Table VIII. Not
only do our targets and matches have a broad distribution of takeover
probabilities, but they are also broadly distributed in terms of size. Arguably,
our sample is diversified and representative.
The
real power of the propensity score matched sample is that it gives us a range
of takeover probabilities from less than 1% to 71%. This distribution of
takeover probabilities is identical in the target and matching samples by
design. We break the sample in half, with one group having a greater
probability of being acquired and the other with a lower probability. If firms
enact accelerated vesting provisions because they anticipate being acquired,
then we should observe a higher preponderance of accelerated vesting in the
high probability group.
A
t-test for the difference of proportions is reported in Panel C of Table VIII.
Among the targets, we find the opposite of our expectations is true. The higher
probability group has a lower occurrence of accelerated vesting than the lower
probability group (72% vs. 87%). The difference is significant at the 10%
level. More importantly, the same is true about the sample of matching firms.
Again splitting the sample in half at the median, we find a significantly
higher rate of accelerated vesting for firms that are less likely to be
acquired (64% vs. 85%). To be complete, we combine the targets and matching
firms into one sample and rerun the test. Our results are no different. Firms
do not appear to adopt accelerated vesting because they expect to be taken
over. Based on this finding, we conclude that the presence of accelerated
vesting in our sample of acquisition targets is not driven by a selection bias.
Table
IX offers a further comparison of the compensation of the matched CEOs. All of
the data for Table IX are drawn from the ExecuComp database. For target firms,
the data are taken from the last proxy statement filed by the firm. For
matching firms, the data are drawn from the proxy statement filed in the year
in which the firm was matched to a target. For instance, Sears Roebuck and
Company was acquired in 2005. Through our propensity score matching, it had
nearly the same probability of being acquired as BJs Wholesale Club Inc. in
2009. For Sears, we use compensation data from the last proxy statement filed
in 2004, and the matching data for BJs comes from the proxy covering the 2008
fiscal year, filed in 2009.
On
the whole, these two groups seem remarkably similar. For instance, our average
target CEO earned a salary of $739,000 in the year before the takeover, whereas
their matched counterpart earned $738,000. Across all seven of the variables
presented in Table IX, none of the means are significantly different between
the two groups. However, the standard deviations on all but the salary exceed
the mean, often quite substantially. Outliers could have a large impact on the
statistics. To work around the outliers in compensation in Table IX, we also
test for differences of medians with a signed test of matched pairs. While the
median values are smaller, we only find a weakly significant difference in
median bonuses. The results in Table IX reinforce the notion that the matched
sample harmonizes very well with the target firms.
Note
that these CEO compensation comparisons are qualitatively similar if we use the
natural log of the dollar values in Table IX or if we divide each dollar value
by total compensation, such as TDC1 (unreported). Dividing the option values by
the tenure of the CEO to derive an annual figure also fails to produce a
difference between these two samples. Simple transformations of the data do not
change the sign or significance of our findings. Overall, our findings suggest
that any differences between the takeover targets in our sample and their peers
are minimal at best.
|
|
20
|
Financial Management XXX 2012
|
|
|
Table IX. CEO Compensation Comparison of
Matched Samples
|
This
table compares target firms and a matching sample across a number of variables
as described in Table I. Acquired firms are matched to nonacquired firms using
propensity score matching. The significance of the differences of means between
the groups is measured with a t-test, whereas the significance of the
difference of medians is measured with a signed test of matched pairs. Only 91
of the 107 acquired firms are used in this sample as good matches are not
available for the other 16. All values are in thousands of dollars.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Variable |
|
|
|
Targets |
|
Matching
Firms |
|
Difference |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Salary |
|
|
mean |
|
|
739 |
|
|
738 |
|
|
1 |
|
|
|
|
median |
|
|
637 |
|
|
687 |
|
|
-50 |
|
|
|
|
std. dev. |
|
|
349 |
|
|
343 |
|
|
|
|
Bonus |
|
|
mean |
|
|
445 |
|
|
620 |
|
|
-175 |
|
|
|
|
median |
|
|
100 |
|
|
0 |
|
|
100 |
* |
|
|
|
std. dev. |
|
|
725 |
|
|
1,853 |
|
|
|
|
TDC1 |
|
|
mean |
|
|
4,732 |
|
|
6,003 |
|
|
-1,271 |
|
|
|
|
median |
|
|
3,125 |
|
|
3,793 |
|
|
-668 |
|
|
|
|
std. dev. |
|
|
4,935 |
|
|
6,526 |
|
|
|
|
TDC2 |
|
|
mean |
|
|
5,463 |
|
|
5,897 |
|
|
-434 |
|
|
|
|
median |
|
|
2,546 |
|
|
3,592 |
|
|
-1046 |
|
|
|
|
std. dev. |
|
|
8,675 |
|
|
6,522 |
|
|
|
|
Res. stock ownership |
|
|
mean |
|
|
2,774 |
|
|
3,659 |
|
|
-885 |
|
|
|
|
median |
|
|
909 |
|
|
565 |
|
|
344 |
|
|
|
|
std. dev. |
|
|
6,151 |
|
|
7,039 |
|
|
|
|
Unvested Options |
|
|
mean |
|
|
2,098 |
|
|
1,434 |
|
|
664 |
|
|
|
|
median |
|
|
528 |
|
|
238 |
|
|
290 |
|
|
|
|
std. dev. |
|
|
4,087 |
|
|
2,460 |
|
|
|
|
Unvested ownership |
|
|
mean |
|
|
4,872 |
|
|
5,093 |
|
|
-221 |
|
|
|
|
median |
|
|
2,090 |
|
|
1,931 |
|
|
159 |
|
|
|
|
std. dev. |
|
|
7,650 |
|
|
8,283 |
|
|
|
|
N |
|
|
|
|
|
91 |
|
|
91 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
*Significant at the 0.10 level. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
D. Accelerated Vesting as a Proxy?
While
we have framed our Risk Aversion and Incentive Alignment Hypotheses around
equity that is affected by accelerated vesting, these hypotheses could also
apply to equity that transfers to the stock of the acquirer. For instance,
under Incentive Alignment, a target CEO with shares of restricted stock that
will become a yet to be determined number of shares of the acquirer still has
incentive to negotiate for the highest possible exchange ratio in the takeover.
This CEO would rather get 100 shares in the acquirer than 95. It is not
immediately clear why a CEO with accelerated vesting would negotiate
differently than a CEO without. Nonetheless, we find a different response by
the CEOs with accelerated vesting and those without. It may be the case that
our accelerated vesting indicator is a proxy for some other unobservable
variable.
Having
established that our matching samples are similar, we can use this expanded
sample to test whether there is a difference in the CEO characteristics and
compensation structure between firms that offer accelerated vesting and those
that do not. In doing so, we hope to find
|
|
Elkinawy & Offenberg Accelerated Vesting in Takeovers
|
21
|
|
|
Table X. CEO
Comparison between Accelerated and Nonaccelerated Firms
|
This
table compares firms with accelerated vesting and those without across a number
of variables as described in Table I. The firms included in this table are both
targets and their matches. The significance of the differences of means between
the groups is measured with a t-test, whereas the significance of the
difference of medians is measured with a signed test of matched pairs. Only 91
of the 107 acquired firms are used in this sample as good matches are not
available for the other 16. All compensation values are in thousands of
dollars.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Variable |
|
|
Accelerated |
Nonaccelerated |
Difference |
|
|
|
|
|
|
CEO age |
|
mean |
55.6 |
51.9 |
3.7*** |
|
|
median |
56.0 |
51.5 |
4.5*** |
|
|
std. dev. |
6.3 |
6.3 |
|
CEO tenure |
|
mean |
7.3 |
5.3 |
2.0** |
|
|
median |
7.0 |
4.5 |
2.5** |
|
|
std. dev. |
4.0 |
3.6 |
|
CEO duality |
|
mean |
63.0% |
35.7% |
27%** |
|
|
median |
100.0% |
0.0% |
100%*** |
|
|
std. dev. |
48.5% |
48.5% |
|
Salary |
|
mean |
773 |
622 |
151** |
|
|
median |
717 |
500 |
217*** |
|
|
std. dev. |
331 |
370 |
|
Bonus |
|
mean |
495 |
660 |
-165 |
|
|
median |
6 |
90 |
-84 |
|
|
std. dev. |
1,000 |
2,306 |
|
TDC1 |
|
mean |
5,537 |
4,804 |
733 |
|
|
median |
3,896 |
2,496 |
1,400*** |
|
|
std. dev. |
5,825 |
5,771 |
|
TDC2 |
|
mean |
5,984 |
4,630 |
1,354 |
|
|
median |
3,711 |
2,309 |
1,402** |
|
|
std. dev. |
7,940 |
6,566 |
|
Res. stock ownership |
|
mean |
3,439 |
2,476 |
963 |
|
|
median |
807 |
273 |
534 |
|
|
std. dev. |
6,882 |
5,603 |
|
Unvested options |
|
mean |
1,895 |
1,337 |
558 |
|
|
median |
370 |
544 |
-174 |
|
|
std. dev. |
3,727 |
1,762 |
|
Unvested ownership |
|
mean |
5,333 |
3,814 |
1,519 |
|
|
median |
1,923 |
2,053 |
-130 |
|
|
std. dev. |
8,316 |
6,548 |
|
N |
|
|
140 |
42 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
***Significant
at the 0.01 level. |
|
|
|
|
|
** Significant
at the 0.05 level. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
some
pattern that reveals more about the CEOs and firms with accelerated vesting
provisions in place.
We now
split our 182 firm matched samples into an accelerated vesting subset and a
nonac-celerated vesting subset. Comparisons of the CEOs in these two groups of
firms are presented in Table X. There are distinct differences in the
characteristics of the CEOs, but few differences in their compensation
structures. For instance, CEOs with accelerated vesting provisions in place are
older, more tenured, more likely to also be the chairman of the board, and have
a higher salary.
|
|
22
|
Financial Management XXX 2012
|
|
|
Table XI. Probit Model to Predict
Accelerated Vesting
|
This
table reports the coefficient estimates from a probit regression that estimates
the likelihood of an executive receiving accelerated vesting. The independent
variables are described in Table I. Values for Salary,
Restricted Stock, and Unvested
Options are in millions of dollars. Fixed effects are by year and
Fama-French (1997) 48 industries. Robust standard errors are used to calculate p-values (shown in parentheses).
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Dependent variable = Pr(Accelerated) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(1) |
(2) |
(3) |
|
|
|
|
CEO age |
0.042 |
|
|
|
0.041 |
|
|
(0.024 |
) |
|
|
(0.040 |
) |
CEO tenure |
0.062 |
|
|
|
0.080 |
|
|
(0.063 |
) |
|
|
(0.031 |
) |
CEO duality |
0.434 |
|
|
|
0.401 |
|
|
(0.069 |
) |
|
|
(0.098 |
) |
Salary |
|
|
8.613 |
|
0.150 |
|
|
|
|
(0.058 |
) |
(0.977 |
) |
Restricted stock |
|
|
-0.124 |
|
0.057 |
|
|
|
|
(0.491 |
) |
(0.834 |
) |
Unvested options |
|
|
0.135 |
|
0.048 |
|
|
|
|
(0.663 |
) |
(0.913 |
) |
Constant |
-2.156 |
|
0.146 |
|
-2.415 |
|
|
(0.033 |
) |
(0.624 |
) |
(0.029 |
) |
Year dummies |
no |
|
no |
|
yes |
|
Industry dummies |
no |
|
no |
|
yes |
|
Observations |
182 |
|
182 |
|
182 |
|
Wald Chi2 |
20.37 |
|
5.64 |
|
21.13 |
|
|
(0.000 |
) |
(0.131 |
) |
(0.020 |
) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
The
biggest difference we would expect in compensation is in the value of
restricted stock and unvested stock options, which would be directly affected
by accelerated vesting. However, there is no significant difference in the
means or medians of either. It does not appear that CEOs with the largest
unvested equity balances negotiate harder for accelerated vesting.
|
To
further test the robustness of these findings, we estimate a probit model
that attempts to explain which CEOs receive accelerated vesting provisions.
The dependent variable in the probit is equal to one if the CEO has
accelerated vesting, and zero otherwise. The explanatory variables include
the CEOs age and tenure, CEO duality, salary, and the value of the CEOs
restricted stock and unvested options. The results are presented in Table XI.
The coefficients on age, tenure, and duality are all positive and significant
indicating that older, longer serving chairmen are more likely to have
accelerated vesting. Also note that the coefficients on the compensation
variables are not significant in the full regression in the third column.13
Our evidence suggests that the amount of restricted stock and unvested
options that would convert to cash for the CEO under accelerated vesting has
no bearing on whether the CEO has accelerated vesting provisions. As such, it
does not appear that CEOs are more likely to negotiate for accelerated
vesting because they have more to gain from it.
|
These
three significant determinants of accelerated vesting (e.g., age, tenure, and
duality) may collectively describe CEO quality. Older CEOs have more wisdom
and experience than younger
|
|
|
13 Our results
are qualitatively similar if we use the natural log of the dollar value of
each compensation variable or if we divide each dollar value by total
compensation, TDC1.
|
|
|
Elkinawy & Offenberg Accelerated Vesting in Takeovers
|
23
|
|
|
|
CEOs.
The longer a CEO serves the firm, the more they have demonstrated their worth
to the shareholders. CEOs who become chairmen are put in that position
because they have significant value to the shareholders. The main determinant
of the presence of accelerated vesting could be CEO quality, which should
also determine the acquisition premium. One plausible interpretation of our
evidence is that accelerated vesting proxies for CEO quality, and firms with
accelerated vesting provisions for the CEO receive higher premiums as they
have CEOs who negotiate better deals for their shareholders.
|
An
alternative explanation is that age, tenure, and duality describe CEO
entrenchment. It may also be the case that more entrenched CEOs receive the
benefit of accelerated vesting, and these CEOs need a bigger incentive (e.g.,
a higher premium) to give up their entrenched positions. As a result, the
positive correlation between accelerated vesting and takeover premiums may be
due to self-interest, rather than superior negotiating skills. Luckily, in
either case, the shareholders benefit from a higher premium. Greater exploration
of this topic is left for future research.
|
|
Fich
et al. (2011) report that a CEO receives a windfall via unscheduled option
grants in 13% of takeovers in their sample. We find that a CEO receives a
windfall via accelerated vesting in 75% of our deals. Although these two
samples are not mutually exclusive, it is notable that accelerations are far
more common than unscheduled grants and likely play a larger role in the
formation of shareholder wealth. While Fich et al. (2011) find that premiums
are lower in deals where the CEO earns an unexpected equity windfall, we
demonstrate that premiums are higher in deals where the target CEO receives a
cash windfall. The difference in our results may be due to differences in the
ex ante efficiency of managerial compensation contracts. CEOs with
accelerated vesting may have well-aligned incentives before the deal is
struck, whereas CEOs who receive unscheduled grants may have poorly aligned
incentives. We are unable to test this hypothesis as only one of our CEOs
receives an unscheduled grant, but it may be the case that unscheduled grants
are passé. Our sample encompasses the period from 2005 to 2009, but the
sample used in Fich et al. (2011) covers 1999-2007 and Heitzman (2011) covers
1996-2006. It is not possible to see the time trend of the unscheduled grants
in Fich et al. (2011) or Heitzman (2011), so we cannot confirm if, in fact,
unscheduled grants were dwindling toward the end of their samples.
|
In
our reading of SEC filings, we found that many options awarded within six
months of the deal are not subjected to accelerated vesting. For instance, in
the summary term sheet for the acquisition of Centex Corp. by Pulte Homes,
Inc., the reader is notified that, Certain equity compensation awards held
by Centexs executive officers and directors will vest in connection with the
merger, except that awards granted after execution of the Merger Agreement
will not vest upon completion of the merger.14 Centex is
acknowledging that it issued options after the deal was announced, but is not
giving special treatment to those options. Therefore, the unscheduled option
grants described by Fich et al. (2011) are not likely a cash windfall, but
rather an equity windfall, specifically equity of the acquirer. These
circumstances may have created some perverse incentive for the CEO to
negotiate for a lower premium.
|
We
began this paper as a horse race between the Incentive Alignment Hypothesis
(arguing for higher premiums) and the Risk Aversion Hypothesis (arguing for
lower premiums). In essence, the Risk Aversion Hypothesis is a branch of the
Jensen and Meckling (1976) Managerial Interest
|
|
|
14 Centex Corp.
DEFM14A, filed with the SEC on July 20, 2009.
|
|
|
24
|
Financial Management XXX 2012
|
|
|
Hypothesis.
There is also a third hypothesis, developed by Choi (2004), that the payments
created by accelerated vesting result in a tax on the acquirer, forcing the
acquirer to offer a lower premium. Our empirical tests cannot differentiate
between the Risk Aversion Hypothesis and the Tax Hypothesis. However, neither
is supported by our results, so this is not an important issue for us to
explore further.
|
With
a sample of 107 acquisitions completed from 2005 to 2009, we study the impact
of accelerated vesting of the target CEOs restricted stock and stock options
on the takeover premium. We find a positive correlation between accelerated
vesting and premiums. The evidence suggests that accelerated vesting provides
a meaningful incentive for the CEO to negotiate the highest possible premium.
It is important to note that although the results offer strong empirical
support for our Incentive Alignment Hypothesis, we cannot claim that CEOs are
indifferent to risk. Rather, our findings simply suggest that incentive
alignment dominates the effects of risk aversion. Assessing the level of risk
tolerance of target CEOs is beyond the scope of this study, but warrants
further research.
|
Accelerated
vesting may play an important role in keeping the CEOs incentives aligned
with the shareholders, especially as the CEO nears retirement. Anecdotal
evidence suggests that some CEOs nearing retirement try to sell their firm
and receive a windfall as a way to cash out at the end of their career. This
is potentially problematic if the bonus is not tied to an increase in
shareholder wealth. Accelerated vesting does seem to properly align the CEOs
interests with those of the shareholders.
|
Like
Hartzell et al. (2004) and Lefanowicz et al. (2000), our main sample consists
of completed transactions. Although our evidence allows us to conclude that
accelerated vesting is positively correlated with premiums in completed
deals, we cannot say that accelerated vesting is universally positive. It may
be the case that some acquisitions fall apart before they are completed
because CEOs with accelerated vesting provisions push for premiums that are
too large from prospective buyers. Future research should examine how accelerated
vesting provisions affect the value of all firms, not just acquisition
targets.
|
This
paper takes advantage of a recent change in the SECs rules to build a unique
sample. While ours is the first to study the impact of accelerated vesting on
premiums, it should not be the last. As more data become available over time,
future work should incorporate larger samples covering longer time periods
and varying international markets.
|
References
Aboody,
D., 1996, Market Valuation of Employee Stock Options, Journal of Accounting and Economics 22,
357-391.
Bargeron, L.L., F.P. Schlingemann, R.M. Stulz, and C.J. Zutter, 2009,
Do Target CEOs Sell Out Their Shareholders to Keep Their Job in a Merger?
National Bureau of Economics Research Working paper.
Bettis, C., J. Bizjak, J. Coles, and S. Kalpathy, 2010, Stock and
Option Grants with Performance-Based Vesting Provisions, Review of Financial Studies 23, 3849-3888.
Billett, M.T., D.C. Mauer, and Y. Zhang, 2010, Stockholder and
Bondholder Wealth Effects of CEO Incentive Grants, Financial
Management 39, 463-487.
|
|
Elkinawy & Offenberg Accelerated Vesting in Takeovers
|
25
|
|
|
Boone,
A.L. and J.H. Mulherin, 2007, How Are Firms Sold? Journal of Finance 62, 847-875.
Brisley, N., 2006, Executive Stock Options: Early Exercise Provisions
and Risk-Taking Incentives, Journal of
Finance 61, 2487-2509.
Brown, L.D. and Y.J. Lee, 2010, The Relation between Corporate
Governance and CEOs Equity Grants, Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 29, 533-558.
Cai, J. and A. Vijh, 2007, Incentive Effects of Illiquid Stock and
Option Holdings on Target and Acquirer CEOs, Journal
of Finance 62, 1891-1933.
Chi, D.C. and S.A. Johnson, 2011, The Value of Vesting Restrictions on
Managerial Stock and Option Holdings, Arizona State University and Texas
A&M University Working paper.
Choi, A., 2004, Golden Parachute as a Compensation-Shifting Mechanism,
Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 20,
170-191.
Cotter, J.F. and M. Zenner, 1994, How Managerial Wealth Affects the
Tender Offer Process, Journal of Financial
Economics 35, 63-97.
Fama, E. and K. French, 1993, Common Risk Factors in the Returns on
Stocks and Bonds, Journal of Financial
Economics 33, 3-56.
Fama, E. and K. French, 1997, Industry Costs of Equity, Journal of Financial Economics 43,
153-193.
Fich, E., J. Cai, and A. Tran, 2011, Stock Option Grants to Target CEOs
during Private Merger Negotiations, Journal
of Financial Economics 101, 413-430.
Fu, X. and J.A. Ligon, 2010, Exercises of Executive Stock Options on
the Vesting Date, Financial Management 39,
1097-1125.
Harford, J., 2005, What Drives Merger Waves? Journal of Financial Economics 77,
529-560.
Hartzell, J.C., E. Ofek, and D. Yermack, 2004, Whats in it for Me?
CEOs Whose Firms Are Acquired, Review of Financial Studies 17, 37-61.
Heitzman, S., 2011, Equity Grants to Target CEOs Prior to a Merger, Journal of Financial Economics 102,
251-271.
Heron, R.A. and E. Lie, 2007, Does Backdating Explain the Stock Price
Pattern around Executive Stock Option Grants? Journal
of Financial Economics 83, 271-295.
Huang, Y. and R.A. Walkling, 1987, Target Abnormal Returns Associated
with Acquisition Announcements: Payment, Acquisition Form, and Managerial
Resistance, Journal of Financial Economics 19,
329-349.
Jensen, M.C., 1988, Takeovers: Their Causes and Consequences, Journal of Economic Perspectives 2, 21-48.
Jensen, M.C. and W.H. Meckling, 1976, Theory of the Firm: Managerial
Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure, Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305-360.
Laux, V., 2010, Stock Option Vesting Conditions, CEO Turnover, and
Myopic Investment, University of Texas at Austin Working paper.
Lefanowicz, C.E., J.R. Robinson, and R. Smith, 2000, Golden Parachutes
and Managerial Incentives in Corporate Acquisitions: Evidence from the 1980s
and 1990s, Journal of Corporate Finance 6,
215-239.
Machlin, J.C., H. Choe, and J.A. Miles, 1993, The Effects of Golden
Parachutes on Takeover Activity, Journal of Law and Economics 36, 861-876.
|
|
26
|
Financial
Management XXX 2012
|
|
|
Maddala,
G.S., 1983, Limited Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics,
Cambridge, MA, Cambridge University Press.
Moeller,
T., 2005, Lets Make a Deal! How Shareholder Control Impacts Merger Payoffs, Journal of Financial Economics 76,
167-190.
Morck,
R., A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, 1988, Characteristics of Targets of Hostile
and Friendly Takeovers, in A. Auerbach, Ed. Corporate Takeovers: Causes and
Consequences, Chicago, IL, The University of Chicago Press.
Offenberg,
D., 2009, Firm Size and the Effectiveness of the Market for Corporate
Control, Journal of Corporate Finance 15,
66-79.
Offenberg,
D. and M. Officer, 2010, Anticipation and Event Study Returns, Loyola
Marymount University Working paper.
Palepu,
K., 1986, Predicting Takeover Targets: A Methodological and Empirical
Analysis, Journal of Accounting and
Economics 8, 3-35.
Rosenbaum,
P.R. and D.B. Rubin, 1983, The Central Role of the Propensity Score in
Observational Studies for Causal Effects, Biometrika
70, 41-55.
Schwert,
W., 1996, Hostility in Takeovers: In the Eyes of the Beholder? Journal of Financial Economics 55,
2599-2640.
Stein,
J.C., 1989, Efficient Capital Markets, Inefficient Firms: A Model of Myopic
Corporate Behavior, Quarterly Review of Economics 104, 655-669.
Stulz,
R.M., 1988, Managerial Control of Voting Rights: Financing Policies and the
Market for Corporate Control, Journal of
Financial Economics 20, 25-54.
Wulf,
J., 2004, Do CEOs in Mergers Trade Power for Premium? Evidence from Mergers
of Equals, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 20, 60-100.
Zhang, Y., 2009, Are Debt and Incentive Compensation Substitutes in
Controlling the Free Cash Flow Agency Problem? Financial Management 38, 507-541.